0

A Critical Reading on Korean Workers: Students and Workers' Struggles

This essay is an analytical reading on Hagen Koo’s book Korean Workers: the Culture and Politics of Class Formation. It introduces Koo’s main objective and questions, his sociological and theoretical arguments applied to explain Korean worker phenomenon, and how he treats data to facilitate and strengthen his sociological arguments in his effort to answer the main issue addressed in the study. At the end of this essay, I will limit my analysis for practicality on how students have played a very important role using their cultural capital in the process of class formation in South Korea in relation to Koo’s logic dynamic.
Apart from poor and inhumane work conditions, workers’ wages in 1970s were very low and unilaterally decided by the employers. A series of workers’ conflicts and strikes against the hegemony of their capitalist employers and pro-capital authoritarian state in 1980s and 1990s had given rise to the promising and dramatic change of workers’ class, status and identity. Koo in his book seeks to explain why South Korea’s workers turned drastically from docile and submissive workers to become one of the most militant, if not the only, class movements recorded in the modern history of Asia. On the other hand, from his comparative perspective, he advanced the question of why “South Korean workers were far more successful than their counterparts elsewhere in East Asia in developing a strong and aggressive labor movement” (p. 3). Thus, his study deals with the history of South Korean workers and industrialization. Koo emphasizes, however, that this book is not the history of workers and industrialization from the ruling class perspective; it is a history from the grass-root perspective. Thereby, I think, this study is critically done to encounter the hegemony of the ruling class in the working-class literature. Koo explains that because labor does not play aggressive role in development, there has been little attention given to the labor issues in East Asian countries. This leniency is in line with the orientations of several writings available on labor. These writings, as Koo criticizes, do not show enough inclination to show labor issues as a class problem, rather they focus on labor docility, weakness and exclusion from politics. In addition, Koo sees that issues raised regarding labor are too general (i.e. applicable across East Asian countries) around confusion culture, rapid economic growth and role of the state, and this, as a result, fails to properly capture the aggressive labor movement in South Korea (p. 6-7). Furthermore, available literature tends to see the problem from a simplistic, reductionist and essentialist point of view. This less critical and simplistic studies have led Koo to the idea of using comparative approach (e.g. European class formation experiences, and other less progressive class movements in other Asian countries) within historical, contextual and constructivist perspective toward cultural and political aspects that interacted closely to facilitate the dramatically progressive formation of class in South Korea. This implies that this study wants to show that class formation process is not a structurally static and closed-ended process, but it is a dynamic and open-ended one. I think because of this conceptual stand, Koo emphasizes that class formation is not a straight forward process of completion, but it is a back and forth process or a water flow-like process in which the actors intelligibly and consciously negotiate with their real conditions in the process of to be or not to be.  In short, Koo uses the dynamic dialectical logic to explain the process of class formation in which cultural, political and social factors closely intertwined to facilitate the rapid formation of the working class in South Korea. Therefore, throughout his writing, he strongly argues that workers’ experiences of severe aggravation and excessive humiliation give rise to the class-consciousness. However, these experiences, according to Koo, will not bring about expected changes without the existence of other forms of movement resources, i.e. cultural, economical and political.
In addressing his questions, Koo comes with different types of supporting data, i.e. statistics, interviews, news documents and pictures. He deals with these data in a unique way of combining complexity and simplicity with one clear goal - is to support different arguments that he lays out in the book. I think this way of treating data is a necessity required by his theoretical and conceptual approach; an approach not guided by a simple linear logic, rather it is a comprehensive approach that takes the complexity of issues into account in order to bring out better argued and supported explanations.  Such an approach, I think, is not an easy choice to accomplish due to the dominance of positivistic paradigm during Koo’s initial intellectual training (i.e. his graduate). In addition, the non-linearity of thought employed by Koo increases the explanatory power of the study at the expense of its more predictive power. However, this does not mean Koo has not considered social change prediction in his analysis. This prediction effort had been, by and large, made when Koo introduced the issue of undecided features of South Korean working class within national and global context at the last chapter of his book.
My analysis, as I said initially, will focus on how students played a very important role using their cultural capital in the class formation process in South Korea.  In chapter 5, Koo explains
“Entering the 1980s with bitter political experiences and a growing awareness of the need to build broad alliances with other democratic forces in their struggle against the immensely power state, students developed a new orientation toward labor. They no longer look at industrial laborers as mere objects of humanitarian concern. They now looked on them as their most important political allies and as potentially a most powerful force for social transformations … They realized, however, that the power of labor remained only a potential; it had yet to be tapped and mobilized” (p. 105).
Repressive state that was preoccupied with rapid economic growth for the interest of the capitalist and politicians who collaborated to control the majority of the assets or resources in South Korea caused social resentment and depression both at minor (e.g. working places) and macro level (e.g. public sphere). The interaction between students and workers that started earlier in the 1970s has moved to become more complex, from focusing on the humanitarian issues to the democratic and political issues. Students and workers were united by their common goals, namely to enjoy equal opportunities to obtain better life chances as South Korean citizens. This unique combination, according to Koo, was among the reasons why the worker movement in South Korea obtained higher level of strength and quality compared to other industrializing countries in the region. In addition, this more mature worker movement actually was the result of a long-term upgraded process of class awareness socialization by the students who had involved directly and side by side with the factory workers to fight against injustice. These direct working experiences enabled students to be fully committed to the enlightenment process of workers. Furthermore, the extreme level of capital-aligned state’s repression made the student and workers’ intimacy to be unpredictably far more solid and unturned.
Koo argued strongly that it was the close collaboration between students and workers in the moment of political crisis that had made the path of South Korean workers movement very distinctive compared to their counterparts in other Asian countries. However, in his discussion of students and workers, I found two points that are interesting for me to make comments on. Notably, the comments I will make are not directly related to the points he made on the above-mentioned argument, but they are related to his logic dynamic. First, Koo uses the terms ‘intellectuals’ and ‘intelligentsias’ to refer to students, dissident political intellectuals and religious leaders. He emphasized in p. 99 of the book that even though intellectuals played a very important role in the labor movement, they were not the real agents of the struggles; but those female workers were the real agents and those of intelligentsias were only the catalysts. Koo wants to stress the importance of role played by the female workers and he succeeds to do that without underestimating the role played by the intelligentsias. Nevertheless, when students became deeply involved in labor struggles by entering factories, I think, there was a recursive direction of internal capital exchange between workers and students. Empowered and enlightened workers had obtained a certain level of intellectuality through training led by students, students-turned-workers, on the other hand, had gained the capacity of becoming agents of struggle as their counterpart workers thorough work experiences. At this stage, Koo does not seem to have an interest in addressing this issue of agency as he does initially in relation to the female workers and church leaders. Second, Koo talked about Lee, a female student worker, who was not given a leadership role in the union once her identity was revealed (p. 122). Koo did not explore this data further (i.e. why she was excluded by the real workers). I think there was an agency conflict or agency misidentification here. If it is important to clarify who are the agents and who are the catalysts in the initial chapter as he did, it also becomes conceptually important at this stage to identify the agency status, and how it guides the interest relations among actors. Being able to identify the agency issue at this stage, I think, can facilitate to highlight the inter-agent dynamic of the labor movement in the 1980s (e.g. Lee case). However, both points do not deter the depth and the richness of Koo’s significant study on South Korean movements. This study has recorded analytically and critically the most important moment of the labor movement in South Korea and more or less has brought about an important impact on the way people, especially in South Korea perceive labor and political movements in the country.

Sphere: Related Content
0

7 in 10 Americans know very little about Islam

Most recently, former Secretary of State Colin Powell rebuked those responsible for spreading the Obama rumor, adding, "What if he is? Is there something wrong with being a Muslim in this country? The answer is no, that's not America."
It is well-known that most Americans have feeling of hatred toward Muslims, including Muslim Americans, especially after 9/11. This is, according to a Duke University sociologist Jen'nan Ghazal Read, really "exceptional' in a country where social boundary is 'limited' and diversity is welcomed. Read mentions two common perceptions that might have led most American to this negative direction toward Islam and Muslims. First, they are trapped to the illusion of Muslim unidimentionality. They do not understand that Muslims are very diverse. Muslims that are associated with terrorism, like al-Qaedah, are very minor. Amazingly, they can become the most salient brand of Islam. Second, they think that being a Muslim is the only identity that Muslims have. However, Read's finding shows that in general Muslim Americans are just like the mainstream Americans in different aspects of life and attitudes. They have Islam as their common identity, but this identity does not prevent them from being American citizens like others.

Sphere: Related Content
0

Cultural Inequality: Politicizing Personal Experiences

I was born from a farmer family in a rural area of South Sulawesi in Indonesia. When I was at the senior high school, I would love to join a trip to Java in a program called study tour. I was trying to find financial supports from several persons or organizations, including governmental offices as most of my friends did and succeeded. I wanted to make other successful stories like them because I was so naive that I was equal to them, while it was not actually. They had economic, social and cultural capital that I did not have.
My school gave all students a complete proposal for this purpose. I was so optimistic that I would obtain enough amount of money from people to fund my trip as many of those friends had told me their successful stories. At this time, I always defined 'success' around the spirit of working hard. So, I believed that as long as I worked hard, I would make it like them. I moved from one place to other places to show them my proposal for financial supports. I was struck that every one I saw and showed my proposal to him or her asked me the same question, "Who were your parents?" When I told them that I was a son of a poor farmer from a country side. They showed me unwelcome faces and tried to find 'rational' reasons to reject my proposal. They thought that I could not identify their 'bad' and unwelcoming feeling about me.But, I understood that they treated me in that way only because I was a son of a poor farmer. I knew that if I were a son of a rich person or a person who had a good position in a government office, they would have treated me differently and special. As a result, they would provide more than what I wanted. Unfortunately, I am a son of a poor and illiterate man. I knew that they would not give hands to anybody without condition. I knew now that equality in education is false and had led many people to have a false recognition of their position in the society wherein they live. Actually, they always wanted reward from what they had given. When they say 'yes', actually they want something rewarding from you. However, they will not say 'yes' to a poor person like me. From this moment, I felt how difficult it is to be a poor person. The structure of my society built a very thick fence to go thorough for a poor person economically and socially like me. For Indonesian society, I think, this is a very serious problem, especially in education system. We are predetermined to be poor and working-class through educational system. The government always work hard to make the capitalist happy. When the capitalist say, 'we need more workers,' the government without any hesitation say to them 'yes', we will build more vacation schools (SMK) to meet your needs. The capitalist, the noble, and the government work together to make Indonesian people to be slaves and servants using people's taxes. On the other hands, these people are naive and think that to be servants for them are a privilege and prestige. So, what do you think?

Sphere: Related Content
0

Capitalism is NOT the End of History


Several years ago Fukuyama, in coincidence with the collapse of communism in Russia, asserted that capitalism was the end of history. After the economic crisis hit the Unites State identified by the falling market at the Down Street, people highly expected that the $ 700 billions bailout will help 'the capital' to gain back the market. Unfortunately, this bailout has not shown any signs that it will help recover the capital market. The capital has gone too far so that causes the market instability. I think we have to believe that economy has limits, human greed does not have limits. Therefore, market somehow must be intervened based on a collective consensus to control the 'greed' of the ruling and the ruled, or the dominant and the dominated.

Sphere: Related Content
0

Women achieves economic independence in a Iranian Way

Islam should be an underlying principle of every aspects of a Muslim, both man and woman. life. Unfortunately, the attitudes of several Muslim thinkers and Muslims in general do not show original creativity to develop practical ways of life that get along with Islamic values. They like to import everything from the West when they are facing social problems. They think that every problem that they have has its own answer in the West. This example is very clear in the field of women movement in several Muslim countries, like Indonesia., under the flag of feminism or gender study I think we must appreciate what the Iranian society initiate in their efforts to make Islam as their way of life. See this interesting news to think about their creativity. This news contains Western bias, but at least it can make you think and be more creative like Iranian society.

Sphere: Related Content
1

Theories of Social Class: Marx, Weber and Bourdieu

This short article seeks to produce analytical comparisons among Marx, Weber and Bourdieu in the theory of social class. This will proceed with the following sequences. First, it begins by elaborating Marx’s concepts of the social class. Second, Weber’s ideas will be mentioned and explained corresponding to Marx’s in order to reveal their similarities and differences. Third, Bourdieu’s concepts will follow bearing in mind Marx’s and Weber’s. Finally, some analytical responses might occur intermittently throughout this article as an effort of the writer to communicate with ‘them’.
When Marx speaks about class, he is concerned with class struggle as the main, if not the only, resource of social change by which class becomes an analytical tool to comprehend social functions and changes. This class struggle incorporating three main elements (i.e. the means of production, relation of production and the product) is based on economic interest. This struggle, driven by economic interest to have control on the means of production, brings about conflict between the working class and the capitalist. Once the capitalist, the owner of the means of production, has succeeded to take control on the means of production, they automatically become the privileged class. They will use their economic-based class power to control their relations with others in order to support their political, social and cultural interests. Thus, relation to the means of production will not only determine one’s social class or social relation, but it also forms his/her values, norms and religion or social superstructure. In this context, people are designated to a certain social class based on the amount of ownership of means of productions they have regardless of their subjective realities, such as inherited status. Class is determined independently and objectively corresponding to the result of dialectic materialism through an antagonistic, conflictual and exploitative relationship of the human beings called class struggle reflecting an objective social selection. So, the ownership of means of productions is not intrinsically related to the issue of man-to-thing relation, but to the man-to-man relation. One can only determine his/her social relations to others based on the level of access he/she has to the means of production through labor division mechanism that gives rise to the class division.
Increasing exploitation of the dominant class or the capitalist on the proletariat through surplus value expropriation under a capitalistic system pushes the increase of gap between the owner of the means of production and the non-owner. When the two poles are extremely bipolarized, social condition arrives at a point where the working class as the exploited class develops a clear picture of class consciousness that has ability to produce class solidarity. At the same time, an effort to maintain class privilege emerges in the form of class exclusion. By then, the meaning of being in a working class become lived experiences and touches the essence of human beings as species-beings that should have reflected themselves on their own creations. Being exploited through the means of productions by their owners, they become alienated and slaved. These common and shared experiences they have move class struggle from the stage of class-in-itself to a new and powerful stage of class-for-itself. However, common and shared experiences are not enough to realize this transformation; class consciousness and organized political movement must exist in order to be able to make class as an agent of change. Within this bifurcated social system, the state plays an important role on the advantage of the capitalist. They work to protect the economic, political and cultural interests of this dominant capitalist class. This state-capitalist collaboration makes it more difficult for the working class to produce social transformation, especially with a state that is supported by military and has legitimate authority over people. However, Marx believes that in the course of time, stimulated by the working class condition created by the capitalistic system, this traditional class system will be replaced by a class free system or communism.
Even though Weber agrees with Marx that class is based on the economic interest and change happens through conflictual relationship, they have different concepts on social class. While Marx defines class inequality around the relation of production, Weber, on the other hand, in addition to the class dimension within economic order, adds two non-economic-based dimensions that contribute significantly to the class stratification: status group associated with social order and party or power associated with the political order. The three dimensions are not intrinsically reducible to one another, but they are related closely. Unlike Marx, Weber does not define class around the means and relations of productions only, but he takes it further to include market situation by which class situation is determined through competition. When people have causal common interests and the same chances of life, they are found in the same class situation. This class situation is essentially determined by the property and lack of property. The degree of one’s ability to buy or sells goods or services will increase or decrease his/her life chances. Then, further differentiation among the owners or the non-owners of property will occur based on the differences in the types of properties, skills and services one offers to the market. So, one’s market situation is determined not only by the amount, but also by the type and formation of ownership he/she has. In addition, even though Weber agrees with Marx’s notion of economic interest as an unambiguous factor creating class, he disagrees with Marx about the uniformity of class interest and the universality of collective actions. For Weber, Marx is wrong when he assumes that “the individual may be in error concerning his interests but that the ‘class’ is ‘infallible’ about its interests” (Weber, 2006, p. 42). Class interest, according to Weber, is not as simple as it might be thought as class situation emerges based on communalization that does not basically involve an action between members of an identical class, but it is an action between members of different classes (Weber, 2006). When every individual has his/her own unique situation of class, status and power, social bipolarization and communal actions become more difficult to be achieved. Furthermore, in order to be able to function within these multi resources of differentiation, a society needs legitimate power in the form of authority played by a political institution or state through rational-legal procedure. This kind of authority is held by those who have privileged class, status and power situations. Then, how Weber theorizes social change? Social change, according to him, can only happen when the three areas of stratification (i.e. class, status, and power) are closely correlated and an extreme gap between the owners and the non-owners of the property (i.e. goods, skills, and services) in these three areas simultaneously exists. Once this exists, social change preconditions, such as charismatic leadership and clearly articulated goals and ideologies, are more likely to be met. In this situation, the lower class is more likely to question the legitimate authority of the ruling class. This practice, when it is done collectively, cause class conflict that will lead to social change. This conflict, according to Weber, occurs in a cyclically dialectic process and will not end in communalism as Marx says.
One of the main dilemmas in sociology concerns human action (agency) and social structure. How far do human beings control their life conditions? Or is most of what they do the result of general social forces outside their control? In the context of Marx materialistic approach, how the “objectively structured aggregations of position holders” are transformed “into consciously acting collective agents”? Marxian solution of this problem leans to be utilitarian and cognitivistic by which the working class transcends its dominated status to collective consciousness utilizing its cognitive insight into their objective situation in the structure of social relations (Joppke, p. 56). Bourdieu offers a solution based on the dialectical principle ruling the relationship between the individual and the society, between the objective and subjective moments, between the field and the habitus. However, he calls both the objective and the subjective and the field and the habitus as structures. Thus, he eliminates the existing dualism of the agency and the structure which he describes as “everything is not equally possible or impossible” (Bourdieu, 1986, p. 242). Bourdieu explicates this concept by introducing the concept of habitus mediating between objective conditions (structure) and subjective perceptions (actors) to form the unity of class unconsciously (Joppke, 1986, p. 54). In other words, this habitus functions as a mediator to facilitate the indirect causal link between ‘positions in social space and practices’ (Weininger, 2005, p. 90). Structure of the social world, according to Bourdieu, is the real picture of the distribution of all types of capital that determines chances of life. Restricting all types of capital to a single form that is recognized by economic theory cannot account for the structure and function of the social world and prevent the constitution of a general science of the economy of practices as well (Bourdieu, 1986, p. 242). Thus, Bourdieu develops three types of fundamental capital: economic capital, cultural capital and social capital. The last two are capable to be converted into economic capital through certain mechanisms, such as credentiality and nobility. This concept is similar to the Weber’s concept of status and power that can be supported by one’s class power and vice versa. However, Bourdieu objects the treatment of this contrast between class and status as two types of real unities because they always coexist in the same reality. Therefore, Bourdieu leans to treat this contrast as an analytical convenience. According to Weininger (2005), another reason behind this inclination is Bourdieu’s vision of social collective boundary as a fundamental form of politic conflict, and political and scientific interests cannot be amalgamated in sociology (p. 84).  Bourdieu locates economic power, as Marx and Weber do, as the most important factor to determine class position, but Bourdieu introduces symbolic dimensions of the class struggle in the form of class boundaries that is continuously be produced and reproduced by the class members of the dominant class to maintain class distinction from the lower classes and within identical classes. This dialectic process will produce a habitus in a form of system that functions two ways: as a system whereby one organizes his/her own behavior and as a system through which one understands others. This process of functioning occurs in a linguistic market where a dialectic exchange operates in order to enable class replication. This linguistic market determines the price of the linguistic products offered by one’s habitus through its specific system of sanctions and censorship. Thus, each individual who brings his/her own habitus have recognized how much profit he/she can make in the market. This profit level is determined by one’s ability to survive a social change through symbolic relation and struggle utilizing his/her accumulated capital in the linguistic market.
Finally, Marx, Weber and Bourdieu have applied dialectic principle in their efforts to understand social structure and change. While Marx has a focus on the conflictual and exploitative dimension of social class, Weber has a focus on the competitive dimension of social class. Departing from both sociologists’ concepts, Bourdieu introduces new insight into social class by eliminating a rigid boundary between structure and agency through a mediating element called habitus. In addition, he introduces symbolic relations, in addition to Marx’s economic relation and Weber’s differential status to understand and analyze social class.          

Reading Resources:
Allan, K. (2007). The social lens: An invitation to social and sociological theory. Thousand Oaks: SAGE Publications.
Bourdieu, P. (2006). Cultural reproduction and social reproduction. In David B. Grusky and Szonya Szelenyi,  Inequality: Classic readings in race, class, and gender, 257-271.
Bourdieu, P. (1986). The forms of capital. In J.G. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education. New York: Greenwood Press.
-----------------(2006). Distinction: A social critique of the judgment of taste. In David B. Grusky and Szonya Szelenyi, Inequality: Classic readings in race, class, and gender, 287-318.
Joppke, C. (1986). The cultural dimensions of class formation and class struggle: On the social theory of Pierre Bourdieu, Berkeley Journal of Sociology, 31, 53-78.
Koo’s Class Handouts.
Marx, K. (2006). Classes in Capitalism and pre-capitalism. In David B. Grusky and Szonya Szelenyi,  Inequality: Classic readings in race, class, and gender, 21-35.
Parkin, F. (1974). Strategies of social closure in class formation. In Frank Parkin (Ed.), The social analysis of class structure. Tavistock Publications, 2-18.
Weber, M. (2006). Class, status, party. In David B. Grusky and Szonya Szelenyi, Inequality: Classic readings in race, class, and gender, 37-53.
Weininger, E. B. (2005). Foundations of Pierre Bourdieu’s class analysis. In Olin Wright (Ed.), Approaches to class analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press, 85-118.

Sphere: Related Content